Als Basis für eine mittelfristige Schätzung des Qualifizierungsbedarfs erarbeitet das WIFO regelmäßig Prognosen der Beschäftigungsentwicklung
nach Berufsgruppen, Branchen und Geschlecht. Dazu wurde eine modellgestützte Prognoseinfrastruktur aufgebaut. Die aktuelle
Berechnung deckt den Zeitraum 2021 bis 2028 ab und bietet eine detaillierte Prognose für 38 Branchen und 9 Berufshauptgruppen.
Auf Ebene der neun Bundesländer werden ebenfalls neben 38 Branchen 9 Berufsgruppen unterschieden. Bei einem Wachstum der Gesamtbeschäftigung
von knapp 1,1% pro Jahr zeigt sich ein deutlicher Trend zu höheren Qualifikationsanforderungen und zu dienstleistungsorientierten
Tätigkeiten. Akademische Berufe weisen ein deutlich überdurchschnittliches Wachstum auf, während insbesondere Berufe mit einem
höheren Anteil Geringqualifizierter Beschäftigungsverluste aufweisen.
Studie von: Österreichisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung – Austrian Institute of Technology – Universiteit Leiden, CWTS – IDEA Consult – Katholische Universität Leuven, INCENTIM – Solvay Brussels School of Economics and Management
Studie von: Österreichisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung – Austrian Institute of Technology – Universiteit Leiden, CWTS – IDEA Consult – Katholische Universität Leuven, INCENTIM – Solvay Brussels School of Economics and Management
This report maps employment contracts and career models with a view to gain knowledge about where and which groups of researchers
suffer most from precarious careers. It suggests policies to reduce the precariousness of researcher careers and indicators
to monitor progress. It follows a mixed methods approach, using as much as possible internationally comparative data.
Österreich bietet einen hohen Lebensstandard, der sowohl in überdurchschnittlichen Pro-Kopf-Einkommen und einer im internationalen
Vergleich niedrigen Arbeitslosenquote als auch einem geringeren Anteil armutsgefährdeter Personen zum Ausdruck kommt. Der
erreichte materielle Wohlstand beruht auf vergangenen Leistungen, stimmt aber auch für die nähere Zukunft optimistisch. Gleichzeitig
bestehen hartnäckige Strukturdefizite in Bezug auf wichtige Bestimmungsfaktoren der langfristigen Entwicklung. Beispiele sind
die als zu gering empfundene Leistungsfähigkeit des Bildungssystems, hohe Abgaben auf Arbeitseinkommen, als überbordend empfundene
Regulierungen, ein geringer Anteil forschungsintensiver Produktionszweige oder die mangelnde Finanzierung von risikoreichen
Projekten mit großem Wachstumspotential.
This study has been prepared for the Executive Agency for Small and Medium-sized Enterprises (EASME), under Specific Contract
ENT-SME-14-F-S107-SI2-698839 implementing the Framework Service Contract ENTR/300/PP/2013/FC-WIFO on "Studies in the Area
of European Competitiveness" coordinated by the Austrian Institute of Economic Research (WIFO; coordinator: Andreas Reinstaller).
This service contract is financed by the EU Programme for the Competitiveness of Enterprises and SMEs (COSME).
Studie von: Österreichisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung
The aim of this study is to analyse the development of new industrial specialisations and the process of export diversification
both at the country and the regional level for the EU countries over time. It examines to what extent these processes show
path dependent properties, whether persistent development trajectories can be shifted in order to avoid structural traps and
what role related and unrelated diversification play for the economic performance of regions. Overall, the results of this
report and its policy implications underscore that Smart Specialisation policies require a smooth coordination of a larger
set of diverse policy measures that take into account both the local context and all the involved players rather than a perfect
setup of single policies. In particular, the educational system, specialisation patterns in research and innovation, and foreign
direct investments play a key role in diversification processes and should be a constitutive element of Smart Specialisation
policies.
Social scientists have long argued that developed countries are more and more responsible for climate change because they
externalise pollution to less developed countries. This paper offers a way to quantify climate responsibility by calculating
carbon footprints and carbon balances between regions by means of an input-output analysis. We find that regions in the center
of the world economy are increasingly consuming CO2 which was emitted in the periphery. Developed countries exhibit a large
emission balance deficit with the less developed economies. Furthermore, we decompose carbon footprint developments between
1995 and 2007 into three effects: technical progress, shifts in the global value chain and increasing final demand. Our results
show that the effect of technical progress is overcompensated by the effect of increased consumption and value chain shifts.
Footprint growth in the center is strongly linked to additional pollution and technical development in the periphery. These
findings challenge the prevailing view of the potential of modernisation and globalisation with regard to climate change.
Social scientists have long argued that developed countries are more and more responsible for climate change because they
externalise pollution to less developed countries. This paper offers a way to quantify climate responsibility by calculating
carbon footprints and carbon balances between regions by means of an input-output analysis. We find that regions in the center
of the world economy are increasingly consuming CO2 which was emitted in the periphery. Developed countries exhibit a large
emission balance deficit with the less developed economies. Furthermore, we decompose carbon footprint developments between
1995 and 2007 into three effects: technical progress, shifts in the global value chain and increasing final demand. Our results
show that the effect of technical progress is overcompensated by the effect of increased consumption and value chain shifts.
Footprint growth in the center is strongly linked to additional pollution and technical development in the periphery. These
findings challenge the prevailing view of the potential of modernisation and globalisation with regard to climate change.
The economic crisis has laid open deficiencies in the construction of the European Economic and Monetary Union. At its foundation,
it was assumed that monetary integration would reduce the likelihood of asymmetric shocks. The crisis shows, however, that
endogenous mechanisms may even amplify existing asymmetries. Without a lender of last resort, a common regulation and supervision
of banks, a common fiscal policy and a co-ordinated economic policy the European Monetary Union is incomplete. The European
Council and the Commission have proposed reforms for the completion of Economic and Monetary Union. Among these proposals
are the implementation of a Banking Union and an integrated economic and fiscal policy. In the long run, national government
debt is to be mutualised at the European level. A European fiscal capacity shall be combined with an automatic transfer mechanism
between member countries, in order to smooth business cycle differentials. Further proposals are intended to accelerate in
future structural reforms by the member countries along the lines of the country-specific recommendations issued by the Commission
and the Council. A first step towards creating an integrated Banking Union has been taken by the introduction, albeit in an
attenuated version, of a common bank supervision. However, key elements to secure the stability of the euro area are still
missing. Measures recently decided under the acute pressure of the crisis ("Six-pack", "Twopack", "Fiscal compact", "Euro-plus
Pact") are confined to structural reform and have de-facto suspended the operation of automatic stabilisers in the crisis
countries. This severely undermines popular support in debtor and creditor countries alike for Economic and Monetary Union,
to the point of jeopardising its existence.
The economic crisis has laid open deficiencies in the construction of the European Economic and Monetary Union (EMU). As a
consequence, the European Council and the Commission have proposed reforms for the completion of EMU. In a first step towards
an integrated Banking Union, a lighter version of a common bank supervision has been agreed. However, key elements to secure
the stability of the euro area are still missing. Measures taken under the acute pressure of the crisis are confined to structural
reforms and have de facto suspended the operation of automatic stabilisers in the crisis countries.
Die Wirtschaftskrise hat Mängel in der Konstruktion der Europäischen Währungsunion offengelegt. Als Folge legten der Europäische
Rat und die Kommission Reformen zur Vervollständigung der Wirtschafts- und Währungsunion vor. Ein erster Schritt für eine
integrierte Bankenunion wurde durch die Schaffung einer abgeschwächten Form der einheitlichen Bankenaufsicht gesetzt. Bisher
fehlen jedoch maßgebliche Elemente, um die Stabilität des Euro-Raumes zu sichern. Die Maßnahmen zur Stabilisierung der akuten
Krisendynamik beschränken sich auf Strukturreformen und haben de facto eine Ausschaltung der automatischen Stabilisatoren
in den Krisenländern zur Folge.